SOCIAL CHAUVINISM
National chauvinism on the part of nominal (phony)
socialists. This term arose during World War I when Lenin and other revolutionaries
condemned those revisionist “socialists” of the Second International who betrayed the
international proletariat and openly supported their own bourgeoisies in waging war
against other nations. Later on, in the revisionist eras in the Soviet Union and
China, those countries also systematically followed social chauvinist policies.
“[In his work Socialism and War (1915), Lenin] shows that the support of the war by the ‘socialists’ of the Second International was a direct betrayal of socialism. He coins the phrase ‘social-chauvinism’ to denote their policy. Social-chauvinism is defense of the fatherland in an unjust war undertaken by people calling themselves socialists. Lenin calls for a break with opportunism and social-chauvinism on an international scale, and the setting up of a new Third International on a revolutionary basis.” —Maurice Cornforth, Readers’ Guide to the Marxist Classics (1953), p. 52.
“The elements of opportunism that accumulated over the decades of comparatively peaceful development have given rise to the trend of social-chauvinism which dominates the offical socialist parties throughout the world. This trend—socialism in words and [national] chauvinism in deeds ... [Lenin then lists many of the specific social-chauvinist individuals in Russia, Germany France, Belgium, and England —Ed.] ... is conspicuous for the base, servile adaptation of the ‘leaders of socialism’ to the interests not only of ‘their’ national bourgeoisie, but of ‘their’ state, for the majority of the so-called Great Powers have long been exploiting and enslaving a whole number of small and weak nations. And the imperialist war [World War I] is a war for the division and redivision of this kind of booty. The struggle to free the working people from the influence of the bourgeoisie in general, and of the imperialist bourgeoisie in particular, is impossible without a struggle against opportunist prejudices concerning the ‘state’.” —Lenin, “The State and Revolution” (August 1917), LCW 25:383-4.
SOCIAL CONSCIOUSNESS
The sum total of all the acquired ideas, opinions, views, concepts, knowledge,
theories, dispositions, feelings, moods, abilities, skills, arts, practices, habits,
customs and traditions that exist among the individuals in a society and which reflect
the social being of its members (the material conditions of their lives).
SOCIAL CONTRACT
An idealist theory in which society, law and morality are the result of either a
conscious or implicit “contract” concluded among the people, or between the people and
the state. The idea is that humans have agreed to give up some of their personal freedoms
in exchange for a stable and secure political existence. This doctrine is historically
incorrect, in that (among other reasons) it supposes that human society existed in a
state of complete anarchy and bestiality (or alternately idyllic freedom according to
Rousseau) until the “contract” was concluded. It is a crude, early attempt to understand
how slave, feudal and bourgeois society could have developed. The view arose in antiquity
but received its greatest development with the rising bourgeoisie in
Hobbes, Locke and
Rousseau.
See also:
CONTRAT SOCIAL
SOCIAL DARWINISM
The theory that the struggle for existence and natural selection govern social
development. It is an invalid extension of Darwin’s theory of biological evolution to
society. Its most famous exponent was Herbert Spencer, but in
various forms it is still quite popular in bourgeois circles.
See also:
DARWINISM [Quotes by Marx & Engels],
GEOPOLITICS
SOCIAL DEMOCRACY
1. A form of the liberal capitalist welfare state mascarading as genuine socialism.
2. Political parties and movements which have this reformist accomodation with capitalism
as their highest goal.
See also:
COMMUNISM—Aims Of
“In the past, social democracy called for using the state to offset,
correct, regulate, and otherwise manage the workings of capitalism. It sought a
capitalism with a human face: one with fewer inequalities of wealth, income, power,
and access to culture. The state was to manage capital investment, regulate markets,
and shape the distribution of income and wealth: all in the interest of a society
with a deeper and more widely shared sense of community. Economic growth and efficiency,
attributed to capitalism, were to be supported while state policy would prevent or
counteract the socially undesirable consequences of private capitalist production and
commodity markets. State interventionist capitalism was the solution; private
capitalism free of state controls and interventions was the problem.
“The social democratic solution
thus constrained what private capitalists could do in their profit-driven competition
with one another and their profit-driven relations with employees and customers. But
it left them in the position of receiving and dispensing enterprise profits. Social
democracy thus left private capitalists with the incentive to weaken, deflect, or
remove those constraints. It also provided capitalists with the means—their retained
profits—to do so. In a sense, this was the historic capitalist-socialist compromise
of the 19th and 20th centuries. Capitalists could keep their positions as receivers
and dispensers of enterprise profits, but the conditions of those positions would be
constrained by social(ist) welfare state policies.
“Whatever the benefits, this
historic compromise set the stage for new struggles. Welfare states became contested
terrains: social democrats sought to strengthen and expand them, while capitalists
sought to reduce, weaken, or eliminate them. From gains, the trend moved in the
direction that favored capitalists. The trend turned into a rout in the 1970s and has
remained so ever since. The capitalists used their profits to improve their business
prospects and performance by, among other strategies, undoing welfare statism. By
lobbying, moving production outside national borders, immigration, common markets,
media campaigns, and countless other mechanisms, the capitalists succeeded in bringing
social democracy to its current sorry state.
“Even where trade unions and
socialist and communist parties were strong, they proved no match for the profits
capitalists could use against them.” —Richard D. Wolff, Capitalism Hits the Fan
(2010), pp. 36-37. This is an outline of both the theory of social democracy
and of how history has fully demonstrated the flaw in that theory. Social democracy
has clearly been proven to be a major mistake, and a complete dead-end, for the
working class. Of course this inevitable result was already obvious to revolutionary
Marxists such as Marx, Engels and Lenin even at the very start of this whole
disastrous social democratic experiment!
SOCIAL-DEMOCRATIC FEDERATION (Britain)
A socialist organization in Britain in the late 19th century which later merged
with other forces and eventually developed into the Communist Party of Great Britain.
“The Social-Democratic Federation was founded in 1884. Among the leaders there were reformists (Hyndman & Co.), anarchists and revolutionary Social-Democrats, supporters of Marxism (Harry Quelch, Tom Mann, Edward Aveling, Eleanor Marx and others); the last-named group constituted the Left wing of the socialist movement in Britain. Engels criticized the Social-Democratic Federation sharply for dogmatism and sectarianism and for its lack of contact with the mass working-class movement in Britain and ignoring of the specific features of that movement. In 1907 the Social-Democratic Federation was renamed the Social-Democratic Party which in 1911, together with Left elements from the Independent Labour Party, founded the British Socialist Party; in 1920 most of the members of that party helped found the Communist Party of Great Britain.” —Footnote 47, Lenin: SW I (1967).
SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC PARTY OF GERMANY (Sozialdemokratische Partei Deutschlands - SPD)
[To be added... ]
SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC PARTY OF GERMANY — Gotha Congress (1875)
[To be added...]
See also:
GOTHA PROGRAMME
SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC PARTY OF GERMANY — Erfurt Congress (1891)
[To be added...]
See also:
ERFURT PROGRAMME
SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC PARTY OF GERMANY — Dresden Congress (1903)
“The Dresden Congress of the German Social-Democratic Party was held between September 13 and September 20, 1903. The main question discussed at the Congress was the tactics of the Party and the struggle against revisionism. The revisionist views of E. Bernstein, P. Göhre, E. David, Wolfgang Heine and a few other German Social-Democrats were criticized by the Congress. A resolution adopted by an overwhelming majority (288 against 11) said that the Party Congress most decisively condemned the revisionist efforts to alter the former tried and tested tactics of the Party, based on the class struggle, tactics that required the winning of political power by the overthrow of the ruling classes and not by adaptation to the existing system. The adoption of this resolution had a certain significance in the positive sense. The Congress, however, was not consistent in the struggle against revisionism; the revisionists among the German Social-Democrats were not expelled from the Party and after the Congress continued to spread their opportunist views.” —Note 199, Lenin: SW I (1967).
SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC PARTY OF GERMANY — Chemnitz Congress (1912)
“The Chemnitz Congress of the German Social-Democratic Party, September 15-21, 1912; the Congress adopted a resolution on imperialism that described the policy of the imperialist states as ‘a shameless policy of plunder and annexation’ and called upon the Party to ‘struggle against imperialism with redoubled energy’.” —Note 321, Lenin: SW I (1967).
SOCIAL FASCIST
A person, party, movement or ideology, which is socialist or communist in name, but
which in actuality operates in a fascist manner towards
the masses. Most revisionist political parties in power are
social fascists to one degree or another. For example, during the revisionist period of rule
in the Soviet Union (i.e., its last 35 years or so), the Communist Party of the Soviet Union
was a social-fascist political party. In India the so-called Communist Party of India
(Marxist) [or CPM] is a social-fascist party, as its rule and oppression of the masses in
the state of West Bengal has amply demonstrated. (See:
HERMAD)
SOCIAL IMPERIALIST
Socialist (or Communist) in name, but imperialist in deeds. For example, the
Soviet Union, which was a genuine (if seriously flawed) socialist country while Stalin was
alive, became a social-imperialist country when the revisionists
came to power after Stalin’s death. The U.S.S.R. then engaged in a long inter-imperialist
struggle with the U.S. to see which of the two powers would control the world.
See also:
AFGHANISTAN—Soviet Social-Imperialist
Invasion Of
“Glossary: Social-Imperialism
“In [the Peking Review article]
‘Total Bankruptcy of Soviet Modern Revisionism,’ the August 23 article by Renmin Ribao
Commentator, there is this sentence: ‘The Soviet revisionist renegade clique has long ago
degenerated into a gang of social-imperialists.’ [See
Supplement to issue No. 34.]
“By social-imperialism is meant
imperialism flying the banner of ‘socialism.’ In lashing out at the revisionists of the
Second International who supported the imperialist and colonialist policies of the
bourgeoisie, the great Lenin pointed out that these renegades were a gang of
social-imperialists—‘socialism in words, imperialism in deeds, the growth of
opportunism into imperialism.’
“After usurping Party and state
leadership, the Soviet revisionist renegade clique has brought about a restoration of
capitalism in all spheres of endeavour in the Soviet Union. It has at the same time
frenziedly followed an imperialist policy abroad and redoubled its efforts to gang up
with U.S. imperialism in counter-revolutionary schemes in all parts of the world, vainly
hoping thus to redivide the world between them. Regarding a number of countries as
colonial possessions, the Soviet revisionist renegade clique has savagely plundered and
enslaved those countries, and by means of so-called economic and military ‘aid’ penetrated
into other countries and controlled them. Where these Kremlin traitors are concerned,
socialism is only a banner, the actual deed is imperialism. The current armed occupation
of Czechoslovakia is a total exposure of the Soviet revisionist renegade clique as a gang
of social-imperialists, a typical and concentrated exposure of its ugly features.
“Twenty-eight years ago our great
leader Chairman Mao pointed out: ‘... the proletariat of the capitalist countries is
steadily freeing itself from the social-imperialist influence of the social-democratic
parties and has proclaimed its support for the liberation movement in the colonies and
semi-colonies.’ The social-imperialism of the social-democrats has long been cast
into the dustbin by the proletariat and the broad masses of the revolutionary people. It
is certain that the social-imperialism of the Soviet revisionist renegade clique will go
the same way—completely bankrupt.” —Note in Peking Review, #36, Sept. 6, 1968,
p. 12.
SOCIAL JUSTICE INDEX
[Refer to large chart at the right:] This is a comparison of levels of equality and social
justice within the different member countries of the OECD. Of
course no country under capitalism, even the best of them, will have anything close to true
equality or genuine social justice. But this chart demonstrates that many countries,
including those in Scandinavia, rate much higher than the richest imperialist countries, and
especially as compared to the United States. The U.S., though the richest of all countries,
is one of the worst as far as the contrast of wealth and poverty goes; and the current
trend is for it to get worse yet.
SOCIAL KNOWLEDGE
Most human knowledge is social knowledge rather than individual knowledge. That
is to say, no individual knows all that much, often not even all that much about their own areas
of interest and work, their own specialities. But humanity in its collectivity knows a tremendous
amount. It possesses an astounding amount of social knowledge which is expanding every
single day, whether any one individual lives or dies.
Most people in modern society have some few
vague ideas about how internal combustion engines work, and automobile transmissions, and
perhaps even refrigerators, microwave ovens, TVs, and computers. But those who know anything
more than a few abstract principles about automobile transmissions are generally not the same
folks who know the basic principles about how a computer operating system works, let alone
how to cater a big festival or do successful brain surgery. It is almost certainly true that
there is no one single individual who could entirely by themselves design and successfully
build a modern airliner, or an economical and safe railroad bridge across a major river,
or—entirely with their own exclusive ideas—successfully lead a social revolution. Projects like
these require the knowledge of many people working together; they require social knowledge.
New knowledge is likewise most often
created collectively, in a social way. With the rarest of exceptions, no one genius entirely
figures out any entirely new thing or process. They are virtually always based on earlier steps
by others, and later on will virtually always have their ideas improved or extended by others.
This is true in science too. As brilliant as Galileo, Newton, Darwin and Marx were in their
various fields of science, many others came after them to improve upon and extend their work.
New knowledge, like existing knowledge, is largely social knowledge, and not the exclusive
property of any individual.
And yet, strangely enough, we humans often
tend to exaggerate our own individual knowledge and to deny the truly miniscule part of
social knowledge that any one of us actually possesses. No doubt this tendency is even more
pronounced in individualist bourgeois society which is so fixated on worshiping heroes. But
it is a problem in the revolutionary movement too, and a major reason why even the revolutionary
leaders need to regularly use the mass line to learn from the
masses!
“Do you know how a toilet works? What about a bicycle, or a zipper?
Most people can provide half answers at best. They struggle to explain basic inventions,
let alone more complex and abstract ones. Yet somehow, in spite of people’s ignorance,
they created and navigate the modern world. A new book, The Knowledge Illusion: Why We
Never Think Alone (2017) sets out to tackle this apparent paradox: how can human
thinking be so powerful, yet so shallow?
“Steven Slowman and Philip Fernbach,
two cognitive scientists, draw on evolutionary theory and psychology. They argue that the
mind has evolved to do the bare minimum that improves the fitness of its host. Because
humans are a social species and evolved in the context of collaboration, wherever possible,
abilities have been outsourced. As a result, people are individually rather limited thinkers
and store little information in their own heads. Much knowledge is instead spread through
the community—whose members do not often realize that this is the case.
“The authors call this the illusion of
understanding, and they demonstrate it with a simple experiment. Subjects are asked to rate
their understanding of something, then to write a detailed account of it, and finally to
rate their understanding again. The self-assessments almost invariably drop. The authors see
this effect everywhere, from toilets and bicycles to complex policy issues. The illusion
exists, they argue, because humans evolved as part of a hive mind, and are so intuitively
adept at co-operation that the lines between minds become blurred. Economists and
psychologists talk about the ‘curse of knowledge’: people who know something have a hard
time imagining someone else who does not. The illusion of knowledge works the other way
round: people think they know something because others know it.
“The hive mind, with its seamless
interdependence and expertise-sharing, once helped humans hunt mammoths and now sends them
into space. But in politics it causes problems. Using a toilet without understanding it is
harmless, but changing the health-care system without understanding it is not. Yet people
often have strong opinions about issues they understand little about. And on social media,
surrounded by like-minded friends and followers, opinions are reinforced and become more
extreme. It is hard to reason with someone under the illusion that their beliefs are thought
through, and simply presenting facts is unlikely to change beliefs when those beliefs are
rooted in the values and groupthink of a community.
“The authors tentatively suggest that
making people confront the illusion of understanding will temper their opinions, but this
could have the opposite effect—people respond badly to feeling foolish. Messrs Slowman and
Fernbach show how deep the problem runs, but are short on ideas to fix it....” —“Cognitive
Science: Mind Meld” [book review], The Economist, April 8, 2017, p. 75.
[The bourgeoisie worries about this
problem mostly because their primary concern is always to maintain their class in power by
controlling the ideas of the masses, which in some ways is becoming harder for them to do.
From the proletarian revolutionary perspective there is another factor here, however, which
the bourgeoisie of course tries to hide: Despite the limited individual knowledge and
understanding of society by the masses, people also do have a tendency to form a community
of understanding and action around an ever-deeper appreciation of their own group interests.
Once the political education and actions of the masses can be better guided by a political
party led by those whose own understanding of society and how to advance the struggles of
the masses is deeper and more scientific, and essential tools like the mass
line method of leadership can be systematically used, then finally the collective
social knowledge of the masses can be employed in a way which truly does advance
their real interests. The revolutionary party, too, must employ this wider political social
knowledge of the masses, and fortunately there are in fact ways to do this! —Ed.]
SOCIAL MEDIA
See also:
PANOPTICON,
TWITTER
“Social media should not be trusted for information—full stop.” —Imran Ahmed, the chief executive officer of the Center for Countering Digital Hate, on the spread of disinformation about the Israel-Hamas conflict. New York Times, National Edition, Oct. 15, 2023, p. 2.
SOCIAL ORGANIZATION
See:
PRIMITIVE SOCIAL ORGANIZATION,
SOCIOECONOMIC FORMATION
SOCIAL PROGRESS
See: PROGRESS
SOCIAL SECURITY PROGRAM (U.S.)
A government-run retirement program for workers in the U.S. which is paid for by deductions
from paychecks while people are working. The ruling class was forced to institute this plan
during the Great Depression of the 1930s as
part of their social welfare programs of the “New Deal” which allowed them to keep conrol
over society. And while it is quite pathetically inadequate, it does at least keep many people
from starving to death in their old age. The ruling class would very much like to get rid of
this and other social programs (see quote below), but it is so popular with the working class
that they have not so far been able to do so.
“When President George W. Bush had tried to privatize Social Security, a plan pushed by the [ultra-conservative] Cato Institute, he had been forced to retreat in the face of overwhelming public opposition. The reality was that despite mobilizing the Tea Party [a rightist mass movement], the big conservative donors had a number of different priorities from the less affluent followers. Tea Party leaders had deliberately ‘fudged’ their agenda on Social Security in order not to alienate the followers, according to one study. They talked in vague terms about keeping America from ‘going broke’ but avoided specifics. Meanwhile, not one grassroots Tea Party supporter encountered by the study’s authors argued for privatizing Social Security. Entitlement programs aiding the middle class were in fact so popular with most Americans that they were virtually sacrosanct. While rich free-market enthusiasts often favored replacing these programs with market-oriented [i.e., for profit] alternatives, polls showed that virtually everyone was adamantly opposed to the kinds of changes that Newt Gingrich candidly called ‘right-wing social engineering.’” —Jane Mayer, Dark Money: The Hidden History of the Billionaires Behind the Rise of the Radical Right (2016), p. 286.
“Start with Social Security, where the [2024] budget calls for raising the retirement age—already set to rise to 67—to 69 or 70, with possible further increases as life expectancy rises. Until Covid produced a huge drop, average U.S. life expectancy at age 65 was steadily rising over time. But there is a huge and growing gap between the number of years affluent Americans can expect to live and life expectancy for lower-income groups, including not just the poor but also much of the working class. So raising the retirement age would fall hard on less fortunate Americans—precisely the people who depend most on Social Security.” —Paul Krugman, New York Times, National Edition, Oct. 27, 2023.
SOCIAL SCIENCE
See also:
BOURGEOIS “SOCIAL SCIENCE”,
HISTORICAL MATERIALISM,
INTERESTS,
SOCIOLOGY
“Now—since the appearance of [Marx’s] Capital—the materialist conception of history is no longer a hypothesis, but a scientifically proven proposition. And until we get some other attempt to give a scientific explanation of the functioning and development of some formation of society—formation of society, mind you, and not the way of life of some country or people, or even class, etc.—another attempt just as capable of introducing order into the ‘pertinent facts’ as materialism is, that is just as capable of presenting a living picture of a definite formation, while giving it a strictly scientific explanation—until then the materialist conception of history will be a synonym for social science. Materialism is not ‘primarily a scientific conception of history,’ as [the Narodnik] Mr. Mikhailovsky thinks, but the only scientific conception of it.” —Lenin, “What the ‘Friends of the People’ Are” (1894), LCW 1:142.
“SOCIAL STUDIES”
The name given to the political and social indoctrination of students in American high schools.
One major goal in these “social studies” classes is to get students to believe that the United
States is a “democracy”, and that the “people hold
power”, because formal elections are periodically held (and
despite the fact that these elections are virtually always controlled by the rich and the
media they own). Another primary goal is to instill a solid respect for U.S. laws and
government authorities, in order to make it easier for the ruling bourgeoisie to keep the
masses under control. And of course yet another major goal is to instill a strong sense of
patriotism among students with regard to the nation, including
a willingness to support its endless imperialist wars. Capitalism may also be talked
about, though only from a strongly positive viewpoint. Socialism, if it is mentioned,
will be totally distorted and lied about, and will be absolutely condemned. All this is what
is called a “social education” in American schools: It is basically lies piled upon lies.
“Social studies is not rocket science. It’s more difficult.” —Jim
Cameron, who led a committee charged with defining standards for Michigan’s social
studies curriculum, answering divisive questions like whether the U.S. is a democracy
or a republic, quoted in the New York Times, April 8, 2019, p. A3.
[Of course for the
bourgeoisie “social science” is harder than rocket science! It is, after all, a
determined effort to get students to believe things which are both ridiculous and false,
and which (for the largest part of the population) go against their own class interests.
—Ed.]
SOCIALLY NECESSARY LABOR TIME
This is what determines the value of a commodity produced in a society
in which there is the exchange of commodities, and most notably, in capitalist society.
“Socially necessary labor-time is the labor-time required to produce any
use-value under the conditions of production normal for a given society and with the average
degree of skill and intensity of labor prevalent in that society.” —Marx, Capital
Vol. I, Chapter 1, Penguin Classics edition, p. 129; International ed. (1967), p. 39.
SOCIALISM (Socialist Society) SOCIALISM — Contradictions Within “Any kind of world, and of course class society in particular,
teems with contradictions. Some say that there are contradictions to be ‘found’
in socialist society, but I think this is a wrong way of putting it. The point is
not that there are contradictions to be found, but that it teems with contradictions.
There is no place where contradictions do not exist...” —Mao, “A Dialectical
Approach to Inner-Party Unity” (Nov. 18, 1957), SW5:516. SOCIALISM — Wages in Socialist Society “SOCIALISM WITH CHINESE CHARACTERISTICS” “Almost everyone in the world knows by now that China is no longer a socialist
country. Even the capitalists in the West, and the U.S. government, have long since come to
recognize this full well—despite their continuing criticism that China is ruled by what is
still called a ‘Communist’ Party.... “A revealing joke in Beijing elite circles describes how Deng Xiaoping,
father of the past 40 years of capitalist ‘reform’ and economic opening up to the rest of
the capitalist world, assembled two teams, one comprising the country’s best capitalist
economic technocrats, and the other China’s most ingenious revisionist ‘Marxist’
theoreticians. Deng asked the first team what policies the new capitalist economy needed,
and commanded the second team to define those policies as ‘socialist’.” —Adapted
from, “Chinese Politics: On the Xi side, beside the sea”, The Economist, Aug. 11,
2018, p. 33. SOCIALISM, UTOPIAN AND SCIENTIFIC [1880 Pamphlet by Engels] “Of all the works of Marx and Engels, this is probably the best for
the beginner. Written in a very clear and easy style, it introduces the reader to the
basic ideas of scientific socialism. SOCIALIST ECONOMIC PLANNING SOCIALIST ECONOMISM “At the present time, those persons in authority within the Party
who are taking the capitalist road and the very few stubborn elements who cling to the
bourgeois reactionary line, working in collusion with monsters and demons in society,
are using economism to corrupt the masses, disrupt production, undermine the great
proletarian cultural revolution and sabotage the dictatorship of the proletariat. SOCIALIST EDUCATION MOVEMENT “SOCIALIST PLOTS” [According to the Capitalists] SOCIALIST REALISM SOCIALIST-REVOLUTIONARY PARTY “[A] petty-bourgeois party in Russia, which came into being at the
end of 1901 and beginning of 1902 as a result of a merger of various
Narodnik groups and circles. The S.R.s [Pronounced
ess-airs in Russian. —S.H.] saw no class distinctions between the proletarian and
the petty proprietor, played down the class differentiation and antagonisms within the
peasantry, and refused to recognize the proletariat’s leading role in the revolution.
Their views were an eclectic mixture of the ideas of Narodism and revisionism. In
Lenin’s words, they tried to mend ‘the rents in the Narodnik ideas with bits of
fashionable opportunist “criticism” of Marxism.’ [LCW 9:310] SOCIALIZATION OF LABOR “The socialization of labor by capitalist production does not at all
consist in people working under one roof (that is only a small part of the process),
but in the concentration of capital being accompanied by the specialization of social
labor, by a decrease in the number of capitalists in each given branch of industry
and an increase in the number of separate branches of industry—in many separate
production processes being merged into one social production process.” —Lenin,
“What the ‘Friends of the People’ Are” (1894), LCW 1:175-6. SOCIALLY NECESSARY LABOR TIME SOCIETY SOCIETY — As a Mere Collection of Individuals “Nothing is more erroneous than the manner in which economists
as well as [some contemporary] socialists regard society in relation to
economic conditions. Proudhon, for example, replies to Bastiat by saying: ‘For
society, the difference between capital and product does not exist. This
difference is entirely subjective, and related to individuals.’ Thus he
calls subjective precisely what is social; and he calls society a subjective
abstraction. The difference between product and capital is exactly this, that the
product expresses, as capital, a particular relation belonging to a historic
form of society. This so-called contemplation from the standpoint of society means
nothing more than the overlooking of the differences which express the
social relation (relation of bourgeois society). Society does not consist
of individuals, but expresses the sum of interrelations, the relations within
which these individuals stand. [It’s] as if someone were to say: Seen from the
perspective of society, there are no slaves and no citizens: both are human
beings. Rather, they are that outside society. To be a slave, to be a citizen,
are social characteristics, relations between human beings A and B. Human being A,
as such, is not a slave. He is a slave in and through society. What Mr Proudhon
here says about capital and product means, for him, that from the viewpoint of
society there is no difference between captalists and workers; a difference which
exists precisely only from the standpoint of society.” —Marx, Grundrisse,
tr. by Martin Nicolaus, (Penguin: 1973), pp. 264-5. “There is no society, only individuals.” —British Prime Minister
Margaret Thatcher, expressing the extreme bourgeois individualist viewpoint where
everyone is only out for themselves in a dog-eat-dog world, and the actual
relationships which exist in society—including the exploitation of one class by
another—are deemed not to exist. Quoted in Eric Hobsbawm, The Age of Extremes:
A History of the World, 1914-1991 (1996), p. 337. SOCIETY — Dominant Ideas In “If you live in a society where ‘to get ahead’ you must agree that the
world is flat, it is amazing just how flat this round old world will come to seem!”
—Larson’s cogent observation #16. SOCIOBIOLOGY SOCIOECONOMIC FORMATION SOCIOLOGY SOCRATES (469-399 BCE) SOE SOFTWARE “A modern passenger jet employs about 15 million lines of [computer]
code. A mass-market PC operating system has around 40 million lines. Modern cars employ
about 100 million lines.” —“The Growing Threat of High-Tech Carjackers”, New York
Times, March 19, 2021. SOFTWARE — Ontological Status Of “[Most people] don’t really understand what software is. They don’t
really understand what it means to say that software is ‘non-physical’. SOLIPSISM SONNENFELDT DOCTRINE SOPHISTS “Sophists (from the Greek sophos—a wise man)—the
designation (since the second half of the 5th century B.C.) for professional
philosophers, teachers of philosophy and rhetoric. The Sophists did not constitute
a single school. The most characteristic feature common to Sophists was their belief
in the relativity of all human ideas, ethical standards and value, expressed by
Protagoras in the following famous statement: ‘Man is the measure of all things,
of what is, that it is, and of what is not, that it is not.’ In the first half of
the 4th century B.C., sophism disintegrated and degenerated into a barren play with
logical conceptions.” —Note 92, LCW 38. SOPS (PALTRY GAINS) SOREL, Georges (1847-1922) SOUL [Speaking of the “soul” in the sense of the human mind:]
“The metaphysician-psychologist argues about the nature of the soul. Here it is
the method itself that is absurd. You cannot argue about the soul without having
explained psychical processes in particular: here progress must consist precisely
in abandoning general theories and philosophical discourses about the nature of the
soul, and in being able to put the study of the facts about particular psychical
processes on a scientific footing. Therefore, [the Narodnik]
Mr. Mikhailovsky’s accusation [against Marx] is exactly similar to that of a
metaphysician-psychologist, who has spent all his life writing ‘investigations’ into
the nature of the soul (without knowing exactly how to explain a single psychical
phenomenon, even the simplest), and then starts accusing a scientific psychologist
of not having reviewed all the known theories of the soul. He, the scientific
psychologist, has discarded philosophical theories of the soul and set about making
a direct study of the material substratum of psychical phenomena—the nervous
processes—and has produced, let us say, an analysis and explanation of some one or
more psychological processes.” —Lenin, “What the ‘Friends of the People’ Are” (1894),
LCW 1:144. SOUND ARGUMENT SOUP KITCHEN SOUTH VS. NORTH THEORY SOUTH AFRICA — And Colonial Legacy “In South Africa—where colonization, mining and apartheid produced
extreme inequality—white people form 9 percent of the population but own 72 percent of
arable land.” —New York Times, “Finding the Paths Amid the Dust”, May 1, 2022. SOUTH AFRICA — And Israel SOUTH KOREA “In the modern era of capitalist-imperialism, at least from the early
20th century on, it has for the most part proven to be quite impossible for economically
undeveloped countries to break out of this condition and seriously begin to develop their
economies in a major, sustained and all-round way—except through socialist revolution
(as in the case of Russia and China). It is true, as Lenin noted, that the export of capital
to economically backward and low-wage areas does serve to promote the development of
capitalism there to some degree. But that development remains mostly in the hands of foreign
corporations (MNCs), and in a form that serves to primarily promote the extraction of wealth
from the undeveloped country. Independent local capitalist development in these countries is
choked by the stifling domination of foreign imperialist countries and their MNCs. SOUTHCOM SOUTHEAST ASIA TREATY ORGANIZATION (SEATO) SOVEREIGN DEBT CRISIS SOVEREIGN WEALTH FUND SOVIET UNION SOVIET UNION — Economic Collapse Of “By the 1970s the signs of deteriorating economic performance were
accumulating rapidly. Most prominent was a steady and continuing slowdown in rates of
annual economic growth, from a respectable 5 percent in the 1960s to 3 percent in the
1970s to 2 percent or less in the early 1980s. The growth of consumption likewise
slowed amid periodic shortages, longer lines, and endless complaints about the declining
availability and quality of consumer goods. Most Soviet consumers came to depend on
the black market, or ‘second economy,’ which expanded greatly in the 1970s. Social
indicators such as declining life expectancy for males and rising infant mortality rates
gave added support to those who saw crisis in the making. Perhaps most embarrassing of
all was the growing technological gap between the Soviet Union and the West. In 1987
the USSR had some two hundred thousand micro-computers; the United States more than
twenty-five million. Even some of the newly industrializing countries such as Taiwan
and South Korea surpassed the USSR in certain areas of technological development.
Massive Soviet dependence on grain imports beginning in the 1970s was a further
embarrassing sign of economic weakness.” —Robert Strayer, Why Did the Soviet Union
Collapse? (1998), p. 57. “We had plenty of everything: land, oil, gas and other natural
resources, and God had also endowed us with intellect and talent—yet we lived much
worse than people in other industrialized countries and the gap was constantly
widening. The reason was apparent even then—our society was stifled in the grip of
a bureaucratic command system. Doomed to serve ideology and bear the heavy burden of
the arms race, it was strained to the utmost.... The country was losing hope. We could
not go on living like this. We had to change everything radically.” —Mikhail Gorbachev,
Resignation Speech as President of the Soviet Union, included in his Memoirs
(1996), pp. xxvi-xxix. SOVIET UNION — Economic Collapse Of [Erroneous Bourgeois Views] “Starting in the 1980s, economic growth in the USSR became more and
more abnormal. The share of raw-material resources in exports grew while the share of
manufactured goods fell. In exports to developed capitalist countries the share of cars,
equipment, and transportation systems fell from 5.8 percent in 1970 to 3.5 percent in
1985, and in the total exports, from 21.5 percent in 1970 to 13.9 percent in 1985. In
conditions of chronic agricultural crisis, food imports grew sharply, a most important
factor in determining the growth of food consumption. SOVIET UNION — Economic Problems In During the State Capitalist Era “An elderly man from the provinces, visiting Moscow for the first time
in many years, enters a meat store and asks for two kilos of meat. ‘We’re out of meat,’
the clerk tells him. So the man opens a small notebook and writes, ‘no meat.’ Much the
same experience awaits him in each of the other stores he visits, and each time he
dutifully notes the results: ‘no eggs’; ‘no cigarettes’; ‘no cheese’; and even, ‘no bread.’
Soon he is approached by a burly official in a leather overcoat who demands to know what
he is doing. Perhaps he is collecting information for foreign governments to embarrass
the Soviet state. But the man explains that he is merely keeping a diary so he can tell
his wife what he has seen in the capital. ‘Well,’ grunts the official, ‘forty years ago
you would have been shot for that!’ Once more the man takes out his pen and jots in his
notebook, ‘no bullets.’” SOVIET UNION — Foreign Debt SOVIET UNION — Military-Industrial Complex [T]he Soviet military-industrial complex had employed more than ten million
people, directly or indirectly supporting about one-fourth of the Soviet population.”
—Richard Rhodes, The Twilight of the Bombs (2010), p. 133. Rhodes is speaking of
the Soviet Union’s final period. SOVIET UNION — Nuclear Weapons: Development Of [Yuli Khariton was the scientific leader of the project which created the
first atomic bombs for the Soviet Union, and thus functioned as the Soviet equivalent of
Robert Oppenheimer in the American Manhattan Project.] “Academician Khariton told us that
Klaus Fuchs, the German-born scientist who joined the Manhattan Project as part of the
British mission, delivered detailed diagrams and descriptions to Soviet intelligence
officials of the American device tested at Trinity [testing site in New Mexico] on July 16,
1945. He told us that he and other Soviet officials made the decision to build a copy of
the American device (although in the spirit of making scientists work hard and learn in the
process, only a few of his co-workers saw the American diagrams). With great pride, he
stated that by August 1949 they had actually developed a much superior design themselves
right here in Arzamas-16 [the first Soviet nuclear weapons lab, which was directed by Igor
Kurchatov]. The Soviet design weighed half as much and was demonstrated to be twice as
powerful when it was tested in 1951.” —Siegfried Hecker, an Austrian-born American
plutonium metallurgist who became the director of the U.S. Los Alamos nuclear weapons
laboratory in 1985. Quoted in Richard Rhodes, The Twilight of the Bombs (2010),
p. 128. “The Soviet [nuclear weapons] program created huge amounts of weapons-usable
materials, close to fifteen hundred metric tons, enough for fifty thousand to one hundred
thousand weapons. [After the collapse of the USSR...] it was everywhere, at a hundred
different sites across the former Soviet Union, in every imaginable form—weapons, scrap,
acid solutions, waste ponds, waste dumps, fuel for reactors, experimental assembles. No
one knew exactly how much was produced, and it only takes a few kilograms to make a bomb.”
—Siegfried Hecker, quoted in Richard Rhodes, ibid., p. 129. SOVIET UNION — Ocean Fishing Industry “Soviet Fishery and Fishing Fleets SOVIET UNION — Revisionist Seizure of Power In SOVIET UNION — Security Agencies SOVIET UNION — State Capitalist Era “The Soviet Union today is a dictatorship of the bourgeoisie, a
dictatorship of the grand bourgeoisie, a fascist German dictatorship, and a Hitlerite
dictatorship. They are a bunch of rascals worse than De Gaulle.” —Mao, “Some
Interjections at a Briefing of the State Planning Commission Leading Group” (May 11,
1964), SW 9:84. SOVIETS (Councils) SOVIETS — Congresses Of in the Early Years of the Russian Revolution “The First All-Russia Congress of Soviets of Workers’ and Soldiers’
Deputies took place in Petrograd from June 3 to 24 (June 10 to July 7 [in the Western
calendar]), 1917; over 1,000 delegates attended. The Bolsheviks, who at that time were
in the minority in the Soviets, had 105 delegates. The majority consisted of
Socialist-Revolutionaries and Mensheviks. The agenda included: attitude to the Provisional
Govenment; the war; preparations for a Consituent Assembly; and other items. On June 4
(17), Lenin spoke, and on June 9 (22) he spoke on the war [see LCW vol. 25]. The
Bolsheviks moved resolutions on all the main questions. They exposed the imperialist
nature of the war and the fatal results of conciliation with the bourgeoisie, and
demanded the transfer of all power to the Soviets. The Congress passed decisions
supporting the Provisional Government, approved the latter’s preparations for an offensive
by Russian troops at the front, and opposed transfer of power to the Soviets.” —Note 47
to Lenin: Selected Works, Vol. 3 (1967), p. 797. “The Second All-Russia Congress of Soviets of Workers’ and Soldiers’
Deputies opened on October 25 (Novembe 7), 1917 at 10:45 p.m. in the Smolny Institute.
Out of 649 delegates, 300 were Bolsheviks. The Congress represented 318 prvincial Soviets;
delegates from 241 Soviets came to the Congress with Bolshevik mandates. The Mensheviks,
Right-wing Socialist-Revolutionaries and Bundists left the Congress after the opening,
refusing to recognize the Socialist Revolution. The Congress declared the transfer of all
power to the Soviets and adopted the appeal ‘To Workers, Soldiers and Peasants’, written
by Lenin. Lenin delivered reports at the Congress on peace and on the land. “The Third All-Russia Congress of Soviets of Workers’ and Soldiers’
and Peasants’ Deputies opened on January 10 (23), 1918. Represented at this Congress
were 317 Soviets of Workers’, Soldiers’ and Peasants’ Deputies and 110 army, corps and
divisional committees. Althogether there were 707 delegates. After three days the
Congress was joined by the representatives of more than 250 Soviets of Peasants’
Deputies--participants in the 3rd All-Russia Congress of Soviets of Peasants’ Deputies,
which opened on January 13 (26). Of this Congress, 441 delegates were Bolsheviks. Y. M.
Sverdlov reported on the All-Russia Central Executive Committee. Lenin delivered a
report on the work of the Council of People’s Commissars and replied to the debate, and
made a speech before the Congress closed. On the proposal of the Bolshevik group, the
Congress adopted a resolution fully approving the policy of the All-Russia Central
Executive Committee and the Council of People’s Commissars. SOVKHOZ [Plural: SOVKHOZY] Dictionary Home Page and Letter Index
1. [Marxist conception:] An intermediate
and transitional form of society between capitalism and
communism, characterized in its economic aspect by the
principle “From each according to his ability, to each according to his work,” and
characterized in its political aspect by the genuine control and rule of society by the
revolutionary proletariat and its party or parties.
Socialism is still a form of class society,
where class struggle still exists, and bourgeois and proletarian ideology and tendencies
still do battle. The ruling class in a genuine socialist society is the proletariat. But
many countries call (or have called) themselves socialist even though the proletariat
either never had power, or else no longer has power, and where society is not (or is no
longer) advancing towards communism (e.g., China after Mao’s death in 1976).
[On the Marxist-Leninist-Maoist conception
of Socialism, see also: “What is Socialism?”, by Scott Harrison (12/20/14). A
letter to Bob Weil about determining whether a country is socialist or not, and specifically
focusing on Stalin’s USSR and Castro’s Cuba. 6 pages, online at:
https://www.massline.org/Politics/ScottH/WhatIsSocialism.pdf (87 KB)]
2. [Non-Marxist, bourgeois “socialist” or
“social-democratic” conception:] State ownership
of some or even most of the means of production in a society totally
controlled by the capitalist class and run by them for the benefit of their own class. In
no way is this really socialism from the Marxist point of view. [See also:
STATE CAPITALISM]
3. [Non-Marxist, bourgeois “progressive”
or “democratic-socialist” conception:] This even more ridiculous view of “socialism”
identifies it with mere reforms and superficial ameliorations of capitalism. As Eric Foner,
a history professor, put it in a recent public letter to Bernie Sanders in The Nation,
a magazine which (like Sanders) supports this point of view, “As for socialism, the term
today refers not to a blueprint for a future society, but to the need to rein in the
excesses of capitalism, which are evident all around us....” [Nov. 16,
2015 issue, p. 4.]
[Intro to be added...]
See: WAGES—In Socialist Society
The utterly absurd name the capitalist-roaders in China
gave to their new capitalist, and then capitalist-imperialist, system they introduced once they
seized power from the proletariat following the death of Mao Zedong. The phrase is so ridiculous
that in China, especially, it has become an open joke!
“But the CCP itself, and the Chinese
government, still try to keep up the pretense that the country is ‘socialist’. According to
them the Chinese system today is ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’. The Chinese
ruling bourgeoisie fears that openly admitting the obvious—that China is a capitalist
country ruled by its own capitalist class centered in the CCP—would destroy whatever
lingering ‘legitimacy’ that they think they have. Hence the continuing absurd verbal
pretense.
“Only a few revisionists, in China and
elsewhere, have failed to understand this basic situation.
“Consequently, all around the world
(and ... even for growing numbers of people within China itself), this phrase ‘socialism
with Chinese characteristics’ is viewed humorously, as the ridiculous nonsense that it
clearly is. And this has led to the tag ‘with Chinese characteristics’ being tacked onto
other features of contemporary China whenever an element of humor or ridicule is desired.
“A case in point is the small book by
Michael Metcalf, Imperialism with Chinese Characteristics?, which was published in
2011 by the National Intelligence University operated by the Department of Defense of the
U.S. government.... Metcalf’s central thesis is that China is now an imperialist country
(though perhaps with ‘Chinese characteristics’) and that it is rapidly preparing its military
to protect and promote Chinese imperialist economic interests abroad.”
—N.B. Turner, Is China an Imperialist
Country? Considerations and Evidence (2014), chapter 20, online at:
https://www.bannedthought.net/International/Red-Path/01/RP-8.5x11-IsChinaAnImperialistCountry-140320.pdf
A superb summary of Marxist scientific socialist theory by Frederick Engels, which has served
as a concise introductory text on Marxism for generations. It is available online in several
places, including
http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/index.htm
“Its three chapters were extracted
from Engels’ much larger work, Anti-Duhring.
“The chief difficulty which a new
reader is likely to find lies in the Introduction, where a variety of philosophical
views are discussed. In this Introduction, Engels deals with the history of modern
materialism, and then refutes the views of the Agnostics and of the German philosopher
Kant. The reader who finds such discussions difficult should read the Introduction
after and not before the rest of the book.
“The following are the main points
dealt with in the three chapters of Socialism, Utopian and Scientific:
“1. Socialism was first put
forward as the dream of an ideal society—a utopia. The Utopian Socialists (St. Simon
and Fourier in France, Robert Owen in Britain) could not show how socialism was to be
achieved in practice. For they could not point to the social force, i.e. the working
class, whose class interest demanded socialism and whose struggle would bring socialism
into being.
“Engels shows that socialism must
be turned from a utopia into a science, which means that it must be based on an
understanding of the laws of development of society, of the class struggle, of the
contradictions of capitalism, of the role of the working class.
“2. Scientific socialism has a
philosophical basis—dialectical materialism.
“Dialectics, says Engels, means
studying things in their real motion and interconnection. He contrasts this with
‘metaphysics,’ which considers things ‘one after the other and apart from each other.’
“Engels goes on to contrast
dialectical materialism with the dialectics of the idealist philosopher, Hegel.
“3. Marxism extends materialism
to the understanding of society and its laws. It demonstrates that the ultimate cause
of all important historical events lies in the economic development of society, i.e.
in changes in the mode of production and exchange. It is the development of production
and exchange which leads to the division of society into hostile classes and to the
class struggle.
“The task of socialists is not
simply to criticize existing capitalist society as unjust, but to understand the
nature of the capitalist mode of production and its laws of development. The essential
nature of capitalism was laid bare by Marx’s discovery of surplus value.
“4. The fundamental contradiction
of capitalism is the contradiction between the social production which capitalism has
brought into being and the private capitalist appropriation. This contradiction
contains the germs of the whole of the social antagonisms of today. And Engels further
shows how capitalism in its development necessarily passes through periodic economic
crises.
“The solution of the contradiction
can be achieved only when the working class, as a result of its struggle, establishes
social ownership to match social production.
“5. Engels goes on to show how,
with the further development of capitalism, capital becomes concentrated into the hands
of great trusts and combines.
“At a certain stage in this process,
the state must begin to undertake the direction of production. Yet capitalist state
ownership is not socialism, for the workers in state industries are still exploited for
capitalist profit. The taking over of productive forces by the capitalist state does
not solve the social conflicts. It does, however, bring them to a head, and creates the
technical conditions for going forward to socialism. For this it is necessary that the
working class should seize political power, taking possession of the productive forces
and utilizing them, not for capitalist profit, but for the welfare of society as a
whole.
“6. Here Engels deals with the nature
of the state. The state is a product of the divisions of society into hostile classes,
and its function is to preserve the conditions of class exploitation. It has therefore
always been the instrument of the ruling class—in slave society of the slaveowners, in
feudal society of the feudal lords, in capitalist society of the capitalist class. The
modern state is essentially a capitalist machine, the organ of capitalist class rule.
“It follows that when socialism
has abolished the exploitation of one class by another, there remains no more need for
coercion and repression and therefore no need for any social repressive force, a state.
So the state will wither away.
“7. Finally, with the establishment
of socialism, anarchy in social production is replaced by planned organization.
Consequently, instead of being at the mercy of economic forces which they cannot
understand, men will be able more and more consciously to plan their lives and make
their own history. ‘It is the ascent of man from the kingdom of necessity to the
kingdom of freedom.’”
—Maurice Cornforth, Readers’
Guide to the Marxist Classics (1952), pp. 7-9.
[To be added.]
See also:
BALANCES—In Socialist Economic Planning
Economism under the conditions of socialism; i.e., the
revisionist theory that under socialism the primary, or even only, task of the
proletariat is to build up the productive forces. The transformation of the relations
of production and the superstructure is either strongly downplayed or totally ignored.
See also:
“THEORY OF PRODUCTIVE FORCES”. There are
also many articles about economism under socialism in Peking Review during the
GPCR; see especially issue #5 (Jan. 27, 1967) available at:
https://www.massline.org/PekingReview/PR1967/PR1967-05.pdf
“Economism leads people astray,
causing them to pay attention only to immediate, partial interests, while ignoring
the fundamental interests of the proletariat. It is against Marxism-Leninism, against
Mao Tse-tung’s thought, and is out-and-out counter-revolutionary revisionist stuff.”
—Guangming Ribao, Jan. 17, 1967; reprinted in Peking Review, #5, Jan.
27, 1967.
A mass movement launched in 1963 by Mao and the Communist Party of China which promoted
socialist values in Chinese society. As part of this campaign, and in order to start to
break down the differences between urban and rural labor, many cadres from the cities
were sent to the countryside. (This policy was later expanded during the
Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution.)
See:
PUBLIC LIBRARIES [Girlfriend quote]
[To be added...]
“The Socialist-Revolutionaries
agrarian programme envisaged the abolition of private ownership of the land, which
was to be transferred to the village commune on the basis of the ‘labor principle’
and ‘equalized land tenure’, and also the development of co-operatives. This
programme, which the S.R.s called ‘socialization of the land’, had nothing socialist
about it. In his analysis of this programme, Lenin showed that the preservation of
commodity production and private farming on communal land would not do away with the
domination of capital or free the toiling peasantry from exploitation and
impoverishment. Neither could the co-operatives be a remedy for the small farmers
under capitalism, as they served only to enrich the rural bourgeoisie. At the same
time, as Lenin pointed out, the demand for equalized land tenure, though not
socialistic, was of a progressive, revolutionary-democratic character, inasmuch as
it was directed against reactionary landlordism.
“The Bolshevik Party exposed
the attempts of the S.R.s to pass themselves off as socialists. It waged a stubborn
fight against them for influence over the peasantry, and revealed the damage their
tactic of individual terrorism was causing the working-class movement. At the same
time, the Bolsheviks, on definite terms, entered into temporary agreements with the
Socialist-Revolutionaries to combat tsarism.
“The Socialist-Revolutionary
Party’s political and ideological instability and organizational incohesion, as well
as its constant vacillation between the liberal bourgeoisie and the proletariat,
were due to the absence of class homogeneity among the peasantry. During the first
Russian revolution [1905-07], the Right wing of the S.R.s broke away from the party
and formed the legal Labor Popular Socialist Party, whose views were close to those
of the Constitutional-Democrats (Cadets), while the Left wing split away and formed
a semi-anarchist league of ‘Maximalists’. During the period of the
Stolypin reaction, the Socialist-Revolutionary Party suffered
a complete break-down ideologically and organizationally. During the First World War
most of its members took a social-chauvinist stand.
“After the February
bourgeois-democratic revolution of 1917, the Socialist-Revolutionaries, together
with the Mensheviks and Cadets, were the mainstay of the counter-revolutionary
Provisional Government of the bourgeoisie and landlords. The leaders of the S.R.
Party—Kerensky, Avksentyev and Chernov—were members of this Cabinet. The S.R. Party
refused to support the peasants’ demand for the abolition of landlordism, and stood
for the preservation of landlord ownership. The S.R. members of the Provisional
Government authorized punitive action against peasants who had seized landed
estates.
“At the end of November 1917
the Left wing of the S.R. Party formed an independent party of Left
Socialist-Revolutionaries, who, in an endeavor to preserve their influence among the
peasant masses, formally recognized Soviet rule and entered into an agreement with
the Bolsheviks. Shortly [after], however, they began a struggle against the Soviets.
“During the years of foreign
intervention and the Civil War the S.R.s carried on counter-revolutionary subversive
activities. They actively supported the interventionists and whiteguards, took part
in counter-revolutionary plots, and organized terroristic acts against leaders of the
Soviet state and the Communist Party. [Including an attempt to assassinate Lenin
which did succeed in severely wounding him. —S.H.] After the Civil War, the S.R.s
continued their anti-Soviet activities within the country and in the camp of the
White émigrés.” —Note 14, LCW 20:566-567.
[To be added...]
The more or less cooperative organization of people which is necessary to promote their
collective welfare and existence. Some forms of human society are more cooperative and
more beneficial to all their members than are others, but only in a future communist
society and after all social classes have been eliminated, will this be completely
true.
See also:
SOCIOECONOMIC FORMATION
The Marxist view is that most of the time the dominant ideas in any society are
those of the ruling class. This is because those controlling society have by far the
greatest opportunities to promote and popularize their views, and even outright indoctrinate
the people through such things as their control of the media and the educational system.
In capitalist society this means that most of the time the dominant ideas are mostly those
of the ruling bourgeoisie. Fortunately, rare moments do arise in times of social crisis when
the masses can disagree on one very central idea which the bourgeoisie tries hardest
of all to promote: that the capitalist bourgeoisie should continue to rule.
[To be added...]
See also:
GOULD, Stephen Jay
One of the following stages in the development of society:
primitive communalism (or primitive communism);
slave society; feudalism;
capitalism; socialism; and
communism. Except for the first and the last of these, all
are class societies. Slave society, feudalism and capitalism all rest upon the exploitation
of one class by another, though this is somewhat hidden from view under capitalism.
These historical stages have been identified
primarily through the study of European history, and sometimes variations are hypothesized
for other areas, such as the Asiatic mode of
production which Marx talked about at times in his writings. It is more common these
days to view the “Asiatic mode of production” as a variety of feudalism.
[To be added...]
See also:
SOCIAL SCIENCE
Famous ancient Greek idealist philosopher and ideologist of
the slave-owning aristocracy. He was immortalized by his disciple Plato
in a series of dialogues, in which Socrates is the dominant participant. However, it has
never been clear to what extent the words of the character Socrates in these dialogues
actually express the views of Plato rather than the historical Socrates.
It seems most likely that Socrates was a
critic of democracy (even within just the slave-owning aristocracy), and for a time a
group of tyrants led by some of his former students overthrew the democracy in Athens. No
doubt partly because of this, some time after democracy was restored he was brought to
trial on charges of impiety and corrupting the youth, was found guilty and was sentenced
to death. He was given the opportunity to flee, but chose instead to stay and voluntarily
drank the poison hemlock.
Socrates had some personal virtues,
including modesty and intellectual honesty. (This is brought out well in a nice story
written by Bertolt Brecht, “Socrates Wounded”.) But politically and philosophically he was
actually a reactionary idealist, and the veneration of him down through the ages cannot
really be justified.
See also:
Philosophical doggerel
about Socrates.
See: CHINA—State-owned Enterprise
Computer programs. That is, the code, or “instructions”, which control the operation of
computers. This is usually divided into two main categories, first, the system software
(or the operating system) which handles the most basic operations such as the overall
control of the computer and the input and output of data; and second, application
software—such as word processors, database programs, Internet browsers, photo editors,
etc.
There is still widespread confusion about
the true “nature” or philosophical status of software. (See also the next entry for further
discussion of this.) In the graphic at the right, an excerpt from a high-level computer program
which simply swaps the position of two variables, is provided in the C-language in which it
was originally written, then in Assembly language, and finally in machine code (ones and
zeros). This machine code includes both the instructions and the data to be acted on. Even
this final version is actually still an abstraction; as it is fed into the computer this code
actually consists of pulses of electrons (for the ones), or the absence of electrons (for the
zeros). Thus software is really just a material substance, i.e., a sequence of physical
pulses of electrons with appropriate gaps in between the pulses. [Graphic is
from the textbook by David Patterson & John Hennessy, Computer Organization & Design: The
Hardware/Software Interface, 2nd ed., (San Francisco: Morgan Kaufmann, 1998), p. 7. As the
text also states: “To actually speak to an electronic machine, you need to send electrical
signals.” [p. 5] (It is true, however, that these days you can use voice input, or other forms
of input, but all of which then still gets translated into electrical signals.)]
What sort of thing is software anyway? For many people, hardware is the physical
machine itself and software is the set of “immaterial instructions” that control the material
hardware. This conception is analogous to that of brain and mind, where “mind” is also
viewed as immaterial. This is a good analogy, but in both cases (hardware/software and
brain/mind) there is something of extreme importance that is not commonly understood: namely,
that both software and also mind of necessity must have a physical basis. Although
we usually think of computers as a combination of both physical and “non-physical”
components (hardware and software), in reality they are really completely physical
(materialist) systems, one part of which (software)—for reasons of our own convenience—we are
usually inclined to think of not in terms of its physical makeup, but rather in terms of how
it functions logically within the computing system. This is further explicated in the quotation
below.
“Ultimately, all software has a
physical basis, even if we do reasonably think of it as ‘non-physical’ in contrast to
hardware—which is undeniably physical. The programs and data running on a PC, for example,
consist of electrical pulses, which are moving groups of electrons—physical things.
Non-running programs and data are usually recorded in the form of physical modifications
to the polarity of the magnetic material on the hard disk, or floppy disk, or backup tape.
Of course, software can be kept in other ways, such as in the pattern of physical pits in
plastic on a CD-ROM platter, or even as ink on paper. But all software has some kind of
physical basis. (Even computer software that we humans are only thinking about writing
already has a more or less sketchy material basis, though so far only in our brains.)
There is no such thing as software which is not encoded physically in some way. There
cannot conceivably be any such thing!...
“But if all software ultimately has
a physical basis, what does it really mean to say that it is ‘non-physical’ in comparison
with hardware? What the heck is the real difference between software and hardware?? In the
final analysis, it is merely a distinction drawn for our own convenience in conceptualizing
the operation of a complex machine of a certain type. Software is part of the computer
system just as hardware is, but it is an abstract conception of part of that system based
on its logical function rather than on its physical embodiment.
“There are intermediate cases between
software and hardware, which are often called ‘firmware’. Part of the operating system in
a PC is contained within a silicon chip, rather than on the hard disk with most of the
programs.... It doesn’t matter to the logical functioning of the system; one way is a good
as another....
“It is entirely possible to construct
a computer that has no software whatsoever (in the usual sense). In fact, the very first
‘giant brain’ digital computers did not need or use any software! They were ‘reprogrammed’
by changing the hardware, by actually replugging the old-style telephone exchange connections
between the physical components (relays, tubes and subassemblies of these).... Reprogramming
a computer in this way is essentially the same as rebuilding it.
“Needless to say, programming computers
through such cumbersome physical modifications was slow, difficult, and error-prone work.
So better ways were found, ways that allow us to reprogram through the physical pressure of
finger tips on typewriter keyboards. We are still making physical changes somewhere (in
magnetic domains out on the hard disk for example), but it doesn’t seem like it! We
are not thinking about magnetic patterns of physical materials at all, but rather about the
logical flow of the program, arithmetical processes, the tasks of various subroutines, and
so forth. We are thinking at a higher level, in terms of abstractions.
“At bottom, when we reprogram a computer
in this easier way we are still rebuilding it; we are still changing the physical
structure of the computing system as a whole. Ordinarily we don’t think of it this way, nor
should we; but when you analyze the situation you will see that that is what it amounts to.
“When we program, it doesn’t seem like
we are actually just modifying the physical world in small but definite ways, nor is there
any reason why it should seem like it at the time! It would be ridiculous to be thinking
at the level of the physical changes which are taking place out on some hard disk, because
that would prevent us from thinking at the level of abstraction which is necessary for
any kind of complicated programming. Abstraction is necessary in order to think about
many kinds of complicated things, including computer systems (and human beings!). If we could
not think about computers in terms of logical processes, arithmetical operations, subroutine
functions and—more importantly—in terms of program goals and purposes, then we could not
make or use computers at all.
“Computers are able to operate according
to logical principles (whether in the form of hardware or software) because logic itself can
be modeled or embodied in physical systems. Not only that, but logic can only be
modeled, reflected, utilized—or even just thought about—in systems with a physical basis.
(Such as human beings.)”
—Scott Harrison, “On the Analogy
Between Mind/Brain and Software/Hardware” (1992), online at:
https://www.massline.org/Philosophy/ScottH/mindsoft.htm [As this paper argues, the
fundamentally materialist nature of software is an important issue primarily because it helps
clarify, by analogy, that mind also has a fundamentally materialist nature. —Ed.]
The crazy idealist view that there is only one thinker in the world, me!, and
that everyone and everything else is a figment of my imagination. This is the most extreme,
most consistent, and most absurd form of idealism. It is doubtful if anyone has ever really
taken this idea seriously, but bourgeois philosophers talk about it a lot since many of
them seem to think it is difficult or impossible to refute the notion!
See also:
VIRTUAL REALITY — Could What We Take to Be the Real World Actually Be a Virtual Simulation?,
and Philosophical doggerel on the topic.
One name for a status-quo point of view with some considerable currency within the U.S.
government at times during the Cold War with the Soviet Union, that each of the two
superpowers had “legitimate” spheres of influence (countries under their own domination),
which—for the good of both sides—should remain stable and not be interfered with by the
other superpower. The opposing view among many of the strategists in both imperialist camps
was that the conflict between the U.S. and the Soviet Union was ultimately a fight to the
death, and that every effort should be made to undermine the stability of the opponent’s
colonies and spheres of influence—regardless of the possible consequences.
Helmut Sonnenfeldt was a councellor to the
U.S. State Department in the Ford administration. At a meeting in London of the U.S.
ambassadors to European countries, which was called by Secretary of State Henry Kissinger
in December 1975, Sonnenfeldt stated: “The Soviets’ inability to acquire loyalty in Eastern
Europe is an unfortunate historical failure, because Eastern Europe is within their scope
and area of natural interest.” He added that “there is no way to prevent the emergence of
the Soviet Union as a superpower” and “It must be our [U.S.] policy to strive for an
evolution that makes the relationship between the Eastern Europeans and the Soviet Union an
organic one ... so that Soviet-East European relations will not sooner or later explode,
causing World War III.” It was said in U.S. press reports that this also reflected
Kissinger’s view. More warlike U.S. imperialist strategists thought this amounted to a
form of appeasement, however.
See:
ALL POWER TO THE PEOPLE! (Lenin quote)
French social philosopher and theoretician of syndicalism and
revolutionary violence.
In the 1890s Sorel first adopted something of a
semi-Marxist perspective, and became involved in support for trade unions, labor struggles, and
reformist social-democracy of the sort championed by the revisionist
Eduard Bernstein. To his credit he soon became disillusioned
with that approach, but unfortunately seemed to lose his political bearings. He then rejected as
“myths” the Marxist ideas that capitalism was eventually doomed for economic and social reasons.
He became much more pessimistic and felt that the working class should not pay much attention to
day-to-day class struggle, or even to exceptional mass struggles such as general strikes, but
rather it needed to develop representative heroes to follow in carrying out mass
revolutionary violence. So his rather anarchist approach became more of a moralistic one, rather
than promoting a mass class struggle. What he simply could not understand was the logic of any
program of mass resistence, revolutionary education and intensifying mass struggle leading
step-by-step to insurrection. Like many infantile “leftists” today he wanted to jump directly to
violence and insurrection without a substantial period of working class education, organization
and preparation.
Philosophically, Sorel was strongly influenced by
idealism, and especially by Henri
Bergson (whose lectures he attended) and later by William
James and pragmatism. Marxist materialism was alien to his thinking. And in general it
has to be said that his thinking was quite shallow and jumbled.
In his book Reflexions sur la Violence
(1908) [Reflections on Violence] Sorel attempted to combine the ideas of Marx with those of
the petty-bourgeois socialist Pierre-Joseph Proudhon. His proposals
for a post-revolutionary society were for a syndicalist organization of factories and labor. But
since his understanding of capitalism was so shallow and un-Marxist, he could not appreciate that
such an anarcho-syndicalist organization only amounts to “market
socialism” in the end; i.e., a system that must inevitably decay back into ordinary capitalism.
Sorel’s hopes for the arrival of a revolutionary
leader and savior to lead the masses in making a violent moral revolution led him to some enthusiasm
for Lenin and the Russian Revolution near the end of his life. But it is said that it also led him
to support Mussolini in Italy! For this reason Sorel has often been viewed as more of a rightist or
fascist than a Marxist or revolutionary. A fairer assessment is that he was a very confused person
who did not have a clear and deep understanding of either capitalism or the Marxist-Leninist path of
overthrowing it.
After World War I the pre-War infatuation with
syndicalism by a fairly large section of the European working class began to fade, and many former
syndicalists—including a number of followers of Sorel—openly turned to fascism. This has left a
very bad taste in the mouths of Marxist-Leninists for Sorel and his followers. It is often not
clearly understood on the left just how erroneous and dangerous syndicalist notions really are!
1. [In religion:] An imagined immaterial
essence of a human being which God supposedly “puts into” the body at conception or birth
(or sometime in between!), and which “leaves” the body at death to go to heaven or hell or
some other “place”. It is hard for a materialist not to simply guffaw at such a primitive,
absurd and unscientific notion.
2. [In older philosophical speculation:]
An alternative name for what is now more usually called the mind.
3. [In wider use:] Because of humanity’s
religious past, the word ‘soul’ is also used even by non-religious people, but in more
rational (if still somewhat poetic) ways, as in describing the essential aspect or nature
of something as its “soul”. Example: “Her hard work and dedication make her the soul of the
strike support committee.”
See also:
SPIRIT,
IDEALISM—Origin Of [Engels quote]
See: DEDUCTION
A charitable effort to feed unemployed, often homeless people, in order to keep them from
starving to death. Soup kitchens became a symbol of the Great
Depression of the 1930s, but have continued to exist in capitalist society.
See also
FOOD BANK , and the illustration at:
ROBOT (Industrial)
As used by those discussing global politics while desperately trying to avoid using the word
‘imperialism’, the “South” or the “Global South” means the same thing as the term “the Third
World”—despite the obvious fact that there are also many “Third
World” countries in the Northern Hemisphere (such as Kazakhstan, Mongolia and Afghanistan)
and also some non-“Third World” (“Second World”?) countries (such as Australia and New Zealand)
in the Southern Hemisphere.
See also:
NORTH VS. SOUTH THEORY
See: ISRAEL—And South Africa
[Offically called the “Republic of Korea”.] The capitalist regime in control of the southern
part of the Korean peninsula, which was set up by U.S. imperialism (with the assistance of the
defeated but cooperating Japanese imperialist military forces) at the end of World War II,
forcibly splitting the Korean nation into two separate countries. South Korea was for many decades
a comprador state completely subservient to U.S. imperialism.
However, South Korea is a very exceptional example of a “Third World” comprador regime which has
industrialized to the level of an advanced capitalist country. As such, it has in effect become a
second-tier imperialist country itself, with large and growing exports of capital to other
nations.
“However, there have been a very few
exceptions to this general rule which require explanation. A few countries in East Asia, and
South Korea most prominently, have managed to develop their economies even under the
capitalist system. At the end of World War II, when Korea was split into two countries by
the U.S., North Korea was much more developed industrially than the South—which was largely
agricultural. But since then South Korea’s economy has developed in a truly major way until
now the country actually qualifies as an advanced capitalist country. It is too far from our
central topic to thoroughly explore how this was accomplished (let alone what happened to
North Korea!). But we believe the basic explanation is that the two dominant foreign
imperialist powers in South Korea (namely the U.S. and Japan) purposely promoted the
independent development of a capitalist economy there as part of their geopolitical necessity
to halt the advance of ‘Asian Communism’. For example Toyota, the Japanese auto company, gave
tremendous help to the South Korea corporation Hyundai to build its auto division into a
successful car company, even though this meant creating a major competitor to Toyota and the
other Japanese auto companies! This sort of foreign tutelage and the limits forced on foreign
MNCs operating in South Korea (by allowing the South Korean government to establish effective
protective tariffs for example), allowed a national bourgeoisie to emerge in the country and
develop its own locally-based economy.” —N. B. Turner, Is China an Imperialist Country?
Considerations and Evidence, (Montreal: Kersplebedeb Publishing, 2015), pp. 27-28. Online
(in at different edition) at:
https://www.bannedthought.net/International/Red-Path/01/RP-8.5x11-IsChinaAnImperialistCountry-140320.pdf
See: UNIFIED COMBATANT COMMAND
A short-lived and mostly ineffective effort by the United States to create a military alliance
under its direction in Southeast Asia similar to their much more effective NATO alliance in
Europe. SEATO was founded in 1954 and only had 8 member countries, just 2 of which were
actually in Southeast Asia. It collapsed entirely in the aftermath of the Vietnam War.
“Sovereign debt” is debt which is incurred by a country (or sovereign power). Or in other
words, debt which is incurred by some government or governmental entity which has the legal
right to borrow money in the name of the people of some country or region, and whose people
then have the legal obligation to repay that debt. This debt is most commonly in the form
of bonds which the government issues. A sovereign debt crisis, is
therefore a financial crisis wherein a country has borrowed too much money, is at risk of
defaulting on the loans it has already received (or the bonds it has already issued), and
is thus unable to easily borrow more money, except possibly at extremely high interest
rates. Generally a country in this situation must either be “bailed out” by other governments
or international agencies such as the IMF; pay off the debt by just
printing money (which results in inflation); or else must simply default. If it defaults,
however, it will be considered a bad credit risk and will no longer be able to borrow money
in the future, at least until it comes to terms with other countries or the IMF.
See also:
EUROPEAN SOVEREIGN DEBT CRISIS
A investment fund set up and owned by a sovereign nation. In the contemporary world some
countries—especially those enriched by their oil or other exports—accumulate massive amounts
of foreign currency and seek to invest that money in foreign assets (by buying corporations or
stocks and bonds of corporations and foreign governments). The chart at the right shows the
countries with the largest sovereign wealth funds as of December 2016, in trillions of U.S.
dollars. [From the Economist, Feb 25, 2017, p. 77.]
[To be added... ]
[Intro to be added... ]
[It wasn’t socialist
ideology which stifled and bureaucratized the Soviet economy! It was the system of
ultra-bureaucratic state capitalism that arose
in the late 1950s, and got more and more sclerotic over the next several decades. Real
socialism works in the interests of the working class and the masses, and thus wins
their solid support and enthusiastic participation in both production and in managing
the overall state. The so-called “socialism” in the state-capitalist Soviet Union was
nothing like this, and was hated by the workers and the people. No wonder it
eventually collapsed!
[The ruling class in the
state-capitalist Soviet Union could not even imagine what real socialism might be
like, let alone favor a program of implementing it. The only economic and social
alternative to their moribund state capitalism that they could even conceive of was
the somewhat less monopolistic, somewhat less moribund, form of state monopoly
capitalism that existed in the United States and Western Europe. So that is what they
decided that they had no choice but to switch over to. —Ed.]
[Intro to be added...]
“This was when the switch was
turned on the mechanism of the collapse of the socialist system, bring a sharp decline
in production and standard of living.
“The slowed rates of economic
growth in the USSR and in other industrially developed socialist countries were
obvious. But the Soviet leadership did not see this as a challenge requiring decisive
action. A note from Deputy Chairman of the Council of Ministers USSR Vladimir Kirillin
to the USSR government, prepared in 1979, contained convincing arguments about the
growing crisis in the Soviet economy. It proposed cautious measures intended to change
the economic system. [Note: These were primarily measures designed to introduce more
market mechanisms into the Soviet economy, and thus begin to more seriously transform
the existing state capitalism into de facto Western-style oligopolistic capitalism.
However Gaidar here calls these proposed “reforms” a move away from “socialism”
in the direction of a capitalist market system. —Ed.] Gosplan [the state economic
planning agency —Ed.], Gossnab [an agency established to specify economic input norms
—Ed.], and the Ministry of Finance did not support them. The document had no political
consequences.
“The political regime formed in
the USSR and in the Eastern European states it controlled appeared stagnantly stable
to observers within the country and abroad. Very few people in 1985 could have imagined
that in six years the regime, the country, and the empire would cease to exist.”
—Yegor Gaidar, Russia: A Long
View (MIT: 2012), pp. 188-9.
[Gaidar was a bourgeois economist
who during the Boris Yeltsin era just after the collapse of the USSR became the
Minister of Finance in Russia and then acting Prime Minister. This was the time of total
economic chaos in Russia, and the period of one of the modern world’s greatest economic
declines and disasters ever to occur in peacetime.
Gaidar’s explanation for
the collapse of Soviet state capitalism is: 1) to call it “socialism”; 2) to focus on
the failure of this “socialism” to compete with Western-style capitalism, and thus
for Soviet exports of manufactured goods to fall precipitously; and 3) to argue that
the “obvious” solution (in his eyes) was not employed, i.e., that Soviet “socialism”
failed to strongly shift toward Western-style monopoly capitalism by introducing much
greater market mechanisms. In short, from his bourgeois perspective, Soviet “socialism”
collapsed because it did not employ extensive markets, and because the wise advice
of bourgeois economists such as himself to switch to greater market mechanisms was
ignored by Soviet leaders.
The partial aspect of truth to
all this is that Soviet state capitalism was in fact moribund in comparision with
the somewhat less monpolistic Western-style monopoly (actually,
oligopolistic) capitalism and was definitely
losing out in the great economic contest between the two. This, however, in no way
serves to discredit true socialism which was politically destroyed and replaced with
state capitalism by the revisionists in the Soviet Union decades earlier. —S.H.]
See also above, and:
HOARDING PRODUCTION
—Workers’ joke during the Gorbachev
era, quoted in Robert Strayer, Why Did the Soviet Union Collapse? (1998), p. 135.
During the socialist era the Soviet Union had little foreign debt. But after socialism was
transformed into state capitalism by the Soviet revisionists economic problems gradually got
worse and worse. This necessitated the development of significant amounts of foreign debt.
As their economic crisis got really severe during the 1980s this debt began to grow in an
exponential fashion. The chart at the right shows the rapid expansion of the foreign debt of
the USSR during the period 1985-1991. The figures are in billions of U.S. dollars and do not
take into account the Soviet satelite countries of Eastern Europe (which were also in growing
economic crisis). [Source: S. Sinelnikov, Budgetary Crisis in Russia: 1985-1995 (Moscow:
1995).]
From the very beginning of the Soviet Union in the aftermath of the October Revolution of 1917,
and as it built a socialist society during its first three decades, it was forced to fight a
major civil war which included a war against foreign capitalist-imperialist countries which
invaded it. And when that civil war was won and the foreign imperialists countries all defeated
and forced to pull out, it was still necessary to spend enormous resources on building up its
military preparedness and the industrial strength in support of that, in preparation for a
future imperialist invasion that Stalin and the CPSU knew full well would eventually occur. Then
in the summer of 1941 Nazi Germany invaded the U.S.S.R. and of course the world’s only socialist
country had to totally mobilize the Soviet peoples in a colossal war effort to defeat it. Finally,
after that war was won, the new threat from the imperialist U.S.A. arose, and the Cold War began.
So because of all these very negative circumstances, the Soviet Union during the entire socialist
era had to devote truly enormous resources for military purposes, which of course necessarily
led to a distorted economy with a very large military-industrial complex.
After the overthrow of Soviet socialism by
Khrushchev and his revisionist cohorts, the Cold War continued, but now as a very dangerous
inter-imperialist rivalry between the U.S. and the U.S.S.R. and their respective blocs. This
meant that the military-industrial complexes in both countries not only continued, but continued to hugely expand
over the years. By the final period of the state-capitalist Soviet Union this military-industrial
complex had grown so enormously large that it is fair to say that it was by far the most central
and most important part of the entire Soviet economy—even to the point where it virtually
strangled the rest of the economy.
[Rhodes himself then goes on to add:]
“Hecker couldn’t resist asking Khariton why he didn’t test the superior Soviet design
first. ‘He said it was very simple—they knew the American design worked. Given the tensions
between the Soviet Union and the United States at that time, failure was not an option.’
Khariton and Igor Kurchatov had met with Stalin, the Arzamas-16 scientific director went
on, and told the Soviet dictator they’d gone over the espionage information in great
detail and believed they could do much better. Stalin had looked him in the eye and said
coldly, ‘The cost of failure will be proportional to your rank in the establishment.’ Both
scientists understood that Stalin was threatening them with execution if the first test
failed. Stalin’s threat was probably the basis for what Khariton called the ‘folklore’
that the prizes awarded to the scientists after the successful test inverted Stalin’s
threat, that in Hecker’s words, ‘those who in case of failure would have been shot were to
receive the title of Hero of Socialist Labor, those who would have been given the maximum
prison term were to be awarded the Order of Lenin, and so on down the list.’” —Richard
Rhodes, ibid., p. 129.
“At the beginning of the 1950s, the
Soviet Union was an inland and coastal fishing country. Today [1977], its catch is one
of the world’s biggest. According to statistics published by the United Nations Food and
Agricultural Organization, the Soviet fish catch was 5,099,900 tons in 1965, 7,252,200
tons in 1970 and it went up to 9,235,609 tons in 1974. Over 90 per cent of these catches
were made in the offshore waters of other countries.
“In the latter part of the 1950s
through the 1960s, the Soviet Union imported a large number of fishing vessels and by the
end of the 1960s it had set up four ocean-going fishing fleets. Today, it has more than
4,000 fishing vessels with a gross tonnage exceeding 6 million tons. These include 643
giant modern trawlers of 2,000 or more tons each. The rest of the world, on the other
hand, has a total of only 259 such vessels. Of the world’s 3.5 million tons of
fish-processing ships, the Soviet Union takes up 3 million tons.
“Relying on their huge fishing
armada, the new tsars stretch out their tentacles to the Pacific, Atlantic and Indian
Oceans, the Mediterranean and Black Seas and other bodies of water throughout the world.
The coastal third world countries, particular those of Africa, suffer most from this.”
—“For Your Reference”, Peking Review, #27, July 1, 1977, p. 24.
[To be added... ]
See also:
PATERNALISM
There were a series of different security agencies (or at least different names) during the
existence of the Soviet Union, including the Cheka, OGPU, NKVD, and then after Stalin’s death
the KGB.
The Cheka (or Vecheka), was set up in
December 1917 to defend the October Revolution and the young revolutionary government against
the continuing attacks by its enemies, the overthrown Tsarist aristocracy and the bourgeoisie.
Counter-revolutionary activity was forcefully suppressed, and enemy agents were rounded up
and imprisoned or executed. The urgency of this task became all the greater as the “White”
forces launched a civil war against the revolution; as the short-term Bolshevik allies the
“Left Socialist Revolutionaries” turned against the revolution (and attempted to assassinate
Lenin and did assassinate other Bolsheviks); and as numerous foreign imperialist powers
employed counter-revolutionary agents and invaded Russia with their armies. ‘Cheka’ is the
shortened Russian abbreviation of the official name, which translates as the All-Russian
Extraordinary Commission for Combating Counter-Revolution and Sabotage.
The Cheka could certainly be ruthless, as was
necessary given that the country was in the midst of a ferocious class war that was
extraordinarily ruthless on the part of the enemy. But it was kept under the political control
of the Bolsheviks led by Lenin, though this was somewhat difficult due to the decentralized
structure of the Cheka and the chaos of the times. The head of the Cheka, appointed by Lenin,
was the sincere and genuine Polish Marxist revolutionary, Felix Dzerzhinsky. Unfortunately
such principled political leadership of the security agencies did not continue after
Dzerzhinsky’s death in 1926.
The Cheka was as much a Party organization as
a state agency, but in 1922 its functions were assumed by the State Political Administration
(GPU). In 1923 the GPU was renamed OGPU (the Unified GPU). Vyacheslav Menzhinsky became head
of the OGPU when Dzerzhinsky died, and until his own death in 1934. However, he was long in
poor health and much of the actual control of the OGPU was in the hands of Menzhinsky’s deputy,
Genrikh Yagoda. The OGPU was under the People’s Commissariat for Internal Affairs (NKVD), and
therefore the security agencies were often called the NKVD rather than OGPU. By 1928 Stalin
was in complete control of the CPSU and the Soviet Union, and therefore also of the NKVD and
OGPU. During this period the NKVD/OGPU implemented (on Stalin’s orders) the ruthless
collectivization of agriculture (completely failing to use the mass
line) and greatly extended the system of forced labor in prison labor camps. Stalin had
Yagoda replaced by Nikolai Yezhov as head of the NKVD in 1936 and then executed Yagoda in
1938. Although Yezhov denounced Yagoda for carrying out the Great Terror, he then supervised
the even greater period of terror from 1937-38 which is sometimes called the Yezhovshchina
(Yezhov era). Stalin then had Yezhov himself executed in 1940.
In 1941, under the new chairman Lavrenti
Beria, the OGPU was renamed the People’s Commissariat for State Security (NKGB), still within
the NKVD. Further changes of names and organizational relationships occurred in the period
after World War II, but with Beria still in overall charge. In 1953, after Stalin’s death,
Khrushchev and other high-ranking leaders of the Soviet Union staged a de facto revisionist
coup d’état and took over both the Party and the government. (This was apparently aided
by some confusion at the time, possibly due in part to some earlier mistakes by Stalin, as to
whether the Party or the State was in top control.) This coup meant that those state and Party
leaders who ideologically opposed it had to be quickly removed and replaced. But Beria, as head
of the Commissariat for State Security, was in a position too powerful and too dangerous for
the revisionist coup leaders to simply replace him. Instead, he was immediately arrested and
then executed. (The official story, repeated by anti-Soviet historians, is that Beria was
arrested on June 26, 1953, and then tried by the Supreme Court on December 23, 1953, and executed
on that same day. However, there is little if any reliable information about these events, and
it may instead simply be that Beria was murdered without any formal arrest or legal trial on
June 26th.)
The security organizations were then reshuffled
and in 1954 renamed the KGB [Komitet Gosudarstvennoy Bezopasnosti or Committee for State
Security]. This organization and name remained in place throughout the entire revisionist and
state capitalist era of the Soviet Union, until its final collapse in 1991. The KGB was then
split and reorganized into the Federal Security Service of the Russian Federation (FSB) and the
Foreign Intelligence Service (SVR) which continue in post-Soviet Russia.
See also:
KGB,
NKVD,
OKHRANA,
SECRET POLICE
[To be added...]
The word ‘soviet’ means “council” in Russian. During the 1905 Revolution councils,
or Soviets, were first formed in a major way by the workers, peasants and soldiers
to represent their revolutionary interests. After the defeat of the 1905 Revolution these
Soviets mostly ceased functioning. But with the overthrow of the Tsar in the
February Revolution, they sprang suddenly back
into existence as an even greater force. During the course of 1917 they settled down into
being the primary representatives of the workers in their day-to-day struggles against the
capitalists, of the peasants against the landlords, of the ordinary soldiers against the
officer corps, and of all the masses against the flaky bourgeois Provisional Government.
Lenin understood the nature of the situation, that despite the current practice of the
Soviets as reformist or union-type organizations, they in effect formed a
dual power along with the formal Russian government. He
further recognized that because of this, and because the workers, peasants and soldiers
viewed the Soviets as their own organizations which truly did represent their interests
(unlike the government), that an insurrection could be led with a central slogan being “All
power to the Soviets!” And, of course, Lenin proved to be correct in his assessment.
The strategy of working toward the formation
of “soviets” or councils of workers in other countries as a step toward revolution has so
far not been successful, though it was widely attempted—especially in the first decades
after the Bolshevik Revolution. However, in the
advanced capitalist world no other strategy has worked so far either, and it is still quite
possible that something like workers’ councils will once again prove quite useful in
promoting revolution.
“The Second Congress of Soviets
adopted Lenin’s decrees on peace and on the land, and formed the first Soviet Government,
the Council of People’s Commissars. Lenin was elected Chairman of the Council of People’s
Commissars. The Congress elected the All-Russia Central Executive Committee consisting of
101 persons, including 62 Bolsheviks and 29 Left S.R.s [Socialist-Revolutionaries]. The
Congress closed at 5:15 a.m. on October 27 (November 9), 1917.” —Note 48 to Lenin:
Selected Works, Vol. 3 (1967), p. 797.
“On January 12 (25), 1918, the
Congress endorsed the ‘Declaration of Rights of the Working and Exploited People’,
written by Lenin.
“During the Congress, the number
of delegates continually increased; at the last sitting 1,587 delegates with the right
to vote were present. The Congress elected an All-Russia Central Executive Committee
of 306 members. The Congress ended on January 18 (31), 1918.” —Note 49 to Lenin:
Selected Works, Vol. 3 (1967), p. 797-8.
[Russian: Literally ‘soviet farm’] State farms in the Soviet Union, or sometimes similar
farms in other countries, as contrasted with kolkhozy
(collective farms).
The workers on these state farms were
called and viewed as just that—workers, and not peasants. They were paid wages,
as opposed to the cooperative-style sharing of production on the kolkhozy. But in some
ways there were still feudal aspects (sometimes described by critics as “neo-serfdom”) to
the workers’ existence on both sovkhozy and kolkhozy. The system of internal passports
prevented even the workers on state farms from leaving that work and moving to the city
for manufacturing jobs.
A state-appointed director managed each
sovkhoz, and capital investment funds mostly came from the state. The state usually paid
less for produce and crops raised on sovkhozy than they did for the same crops raised by
kolkhozy. But due to the greater capital investment, the larger size and usually greater
efficiency of the sovkhozy, at least in the period after World War II these state farms
where overall in a better position financially.
Sovkhozy were first created in the early
1920s, generally on large estates formerly belonging to the Tsar or other nobility. The
kolkhozy, in contrast, were generally organized through the collectivization of numerous
small peasant holdings. Kolkhozy were viewed (quite appropriately) as intermediate forms
between individual private farming of land and the more fully socialist state farms, and
it was originally expected that all the kolkhozy would be transformed into sovkhozy in a
short time. However, during the late 1920s and early 1930s, kolkhozy became viewed as
more important than previously and for a while their transformation into sovkhozy was
drastically slowed down. Still the long-term trend was toward the transformation of
cooperative farms into state farms, and this rate of transformation became faster after
World War II. The revisionists, who seized power in the mid-1950s, continued this
transformation policy, but not for ideological reasons. They viewed state farms as more
profitable.
The number of sovkhozy in the Soviet
Union grew from about 1,500 in 1929 to over 23,000 by the late 1980s. The size of state
farms also grew, though even in the mid-1920s they were sometimes of enormous size. In
the 1930s the average sown area of state farms was about 3,600 hectares (6,000 acres),
and by the 1980s the average sown area had grown to 4,500 hectares (11,000 acres). In
1990, near the end of the existence of the U.S.S.R., sovkhozy were 45% of the total
number of state and collective farms added together. After the collapse of the Soviet
Union, and amidst the general transformation state capitalism into Western-style
monopoly capitalism, many state farms were reorganized as capitalist corporations.